Recent Posts

Showing posts with label JGB Collapse. Show all posts
Showing posts with label JGB Collapse. Show all posts

Wednesday, December 28, 2016

Happy New Year!



Happy New Year to all of my readers! Once again, the JGB market has defied predictions of imminent collapse in 2016, but perhaps Santa Claus will bring presents for suffering JGB bears in 2017.

Saturday, April 16, 2016

Olivier Blanchard Joins The "Japan Is Doomed!" Crowd

Olivier Blanchard (ex-Chief Economist of the IMF) has been quoted arguing that the Japanese face serious macro risks; in reality, probably the biggest economic risk Japan faces is listening to New Keynesian economists. Ambrose Evans-Pritchard, of the Telegraph, summarised Blanchard's comments at a meeting at Lake Como as "Olivier Blanchard eyes ugly 'end game' for Japan on debt spiral." Although the article only provides a few quotes, the logic is quite weak.

Tuesday, February 23, 2016

Fujimaki: Japanese Hyperinflation! (Again!)

It's been fairly quiet on the JGB collapse front; apparently, people got tired of losing money shorting the things. However, this has not stopped Takeshi Fujimaki from re-iterating his Japanese hyperinflation call.


Friday, January 29, 2016

BoJ NIRP Makes Fed Rate Hike Look Even More Foolish

Chart: 10-Year JGB Yield

The JGB collapse has been delayed yet again. The Bank of Japan (BoJ) has introduced a Negative Interest Rate Policy (NIRP), via a complicated 3-tier policy rate, with one of those rates at -0.10%. Once again, year-end forecasts of higher bond yields have been met with an early bond bull market.

Sunday, December 27, 2015

Happy New Year!

Chart: JGB Collapse! (2016 edition...)

Happy New Year to all my readers! Unfortunately (but fortunately for the Japanese), Japanese hyperinflation and the utter collapse of the JGB market has been slightly delayed, but perhaps 2016 will finally be the year in which the JGB bears can say "I told you so!"

Although the imminent demise of the JGB market ("any month now!") is one thing to watch for in 2016, a potential recession in the United States appears to be a slightly higher probability event to keep in mind. Stay tuned!

Thursday, March 12, 2015

Note To Reporters: You Cannot Analyse A Sovereign Like A Corporation

Reporters and (apparently) readers have a hard time differentiating between the different fields within finance, and so they happily treat comments made by people like internet analysts (!) as representing "what the markets think" about government fiscal ratios. Since bad fiscal analysis is more exciting than good analysis, that is what appears in the media.

Please note that the difference between corporate financial analysis and the analysis of governments is found in the book Understanding Government Finance (link).

Monday, January 5, 2015

JGBs Are Doomed Because Of ... Demographics? Good Grief.

After losing money for almost two decades on the thesis that "the IMF-calculated gross debt-to-GDP ratio for Japan is too high", JGB bears are rotating into another structural thesis why the JGB market must collapse - demographics. (Why German bunds and Swiss bonds are spared from this single-minded hatred of low nominal yields is beyond me.) This complements the pivot towards talking about "yen collapse" instead of a JGB calamity. The problem with this theory is that being worried about demographics is akin to worrying that a steamroller two miles down the road is heading in your direction.


Monday, December 29, 2014

Will 2015 Be "The Big One" For JGB's?

JGB Collapse In 2015!?! (Bond Economics)
Well, 2014 was not a banner year for JGB bears. But based on the theory that things can only get better, it is looking like 2015 could be the year that the great JGB collapse starts. Stay tuned!

Happy New Year from bondeconomics.com!

Saturday, December 27, 2014

For The Japanese MoF, "Debt Service" Does Not Mean "Interest Costs"

There has been a widespread inability to comprehend how the Ministry of Finance ("MoF") uses the term "debt service" in the English translations of its documents. For some unfathomable reason, the MoF includes the rollover of debt issues as part of its "debt service" figure. [Update: This seems to based on the usage of "debt service" as defined for external debt.] As a result, foreign analysts that complain about a high "debt service to revenue" ratio are missing the point. (I would note that I had not seen this error in broker research amongst Japan specialists.)

Monday, December 15, 2014

The 'Widowmaker' And Yen Crash Theories

Chart: Japanese Yen
There has been a recent shift amongst those predicting the collapse of the Japanese economy to switch away from the so-called "widowmaker trade" - short Japanese Government Bonds (JGBs) - towards forecasts of a collapse in the Japanese yen (pictured above). Although this may result from learning a lesson from roughly two decades of failed "JGB collapse" predictions, I suspect that this is the result of learning the wrong things. Being structurally short the yen is hardly the safest trade in the world either.

Sunday, July 20, 2014

The Bond Bear Market Of 2014 Has Been Delayed

Chart: 10-Year JGB Yield
Strategists went into 2014 with a consensus bearish view on bonds (as was also the case in 2010-2013...). The market action so far has not been kind to that view, with yields plunging in the developed markets. It may be that I have fallen into a too mellow summertime mood, but my guess is that this is largely a squeeze of the bond bears during quiet markets (although there are obvious geopolitical concerns).

Thursday, June 5, 2014

Japanese Wage-Price Spiral Theories Not Doing Too Well

Chart: 10-Year JGB Yield
The general lack of a collapse in the JGB market is presumably testing the patience of dedicated JGB bears. This does not appear too surprising, given the stability in wage trends. I find that the complete lack of a term premium in JGB yields somewhat worrisome, given the one-sided nature of the risk distribution. That said, there is no obvious catalyst to force a re-pricing.


Friday, January 17, 2014

Japan Is Running A Current Account Deficit. Where Is My JGB Collapse?

One of the reasons analysts have used to explain what they thought were "too low" JGB yields is that Japan was running persistent current account surpluses. In fact, there was a theory floating around a year or so ago (before this blog was launched) which argued: the Japanese current account was moving towards a deficit and so it would be "Game Over!" for the JGB market when that happened. (Since most foreigners have no appetite to buy JGB's.)  Japan has now been running a current account deficit, but the 10-year JGB is still stuck at a level that even I think is too low at 0.67%.....

Saturday, January 11, 2014

Feldman: Japan Collapse in 2-3 Years Possible

The latest entry to the JGB Collapse prediction list is from Robert Feldman. I do not have access to the original report this is based on, but I have some quotations from a Bloomberg article.

The Japanese government has two to three years to curb expenditures or face a possible crisis, according to Robert Feldman, the head of Japan economic research at Morgan Stanley MUFG Securities Co. 
and

“There’s the risk interest payments would swell should the government fail to cut budget deficits when inflation and yields grind higher,” Feldman said in an interview in Tokyo on Jan. 8. “Absent an increase in tax revenues stemming from a tangible improvement in the real economy, there is a risk of collapse.”
His prediction matches what I think would be the cause of a collapse: rising Japanese inflation forcing rate hikes. I admit that I may be too complacent, but I do not see the current fiscal outlook leading to that outcome in the next couple of years. In fact, I am more worried about the contractionary impact of the consumption tax hike at present. (There will be an element of "bad inflation" that results from the tax hike, which most observers will justifiably make corrections for.)

(c) Brian Romanchuk 2014

Thursday, December 12, 2013

On Kyle Bass And Keynes

 Kyle Bass has provided the latest entry in the JGB Collapse wall of predictions. In an interview in a book by Steven Drobny (in a free chapter available here), he argues that JGB yields are going to 20% and the yen/dollar rate is going beyond 200. In this article, I make a few comments on this scenario, and find that this is a good example of Keynes' distinction between uncertainty and randomness...

Thursday, November 14, 2013

Cry "Havoc!" And Let Slip The JGB Bears!

We have a new entry for the "JGB Collapse" prediction log. In "Why Has Japan's Massive Debt Not Wreaked Havoc (Yet)?", Charles Yuji Horioka, Takaaki Nomoto and Akiko Terada-Hagiwara look at the Flow Of Funds data for Japan. They argue that flows related to the financial crisis have allowed the JGB market to avoid collapse. The article is academic, so they do not have any juicy JGB yield targets.

I am assembling the Japanese flow of funds data on my personal research system. I may take a longer look at this paper once the data are ready. However, I am not convinced by their concerns around the need for foreigners to buy assets to fund a Japanese current account deficit. The Japanese have a very large stock of foreign currency assets, and so there is no need to convince foreigners to buy anything to finance a current account deficit.
 
(c) Brian Romanchuk 2013

Sunday, October 27, 2013

Why Will The JGB Market Collapse?

Chart: 10-year JGB Yield - A Very Slow-Paced Bear Market


In this article I examine reasons why I believe the Japanese Government Bond (JGB) market will eventually collapse. My explanation is simple: the JGB market will collapse when it is in the national interest of Japan for the collapse to occur.

I define a “collapse” as a rise in the 10-year JGB yield to at least 5%, although not necessarily in one fell swoop. This is a move well outside the experience of the JGB market for the 15 years or so. Headline writers may not agree with this, being desperate for snazzy article titles. For example, if the 10-year JGB yield doubled to 1.20% in the next three weeks, the airwaves will be filled with JGB bears announcing “I told you so”. (My favourite potential headline "Japanese bond yields rise by 100%!") But a 60 basis point move that just returns the 10-year yield to the middle of its multi-decade trading range – who cares? I am talking about a serious bear market here.

I am giving a framework for thinking about why the JGB market will collapse, but I am not worried yet about timing. For reasons that shall be seen, I expect that the JGB market will manage to hold on below 5% for a while longer. Pinpointing the timing will require a deeper dive into Japanese data. However, Japanese data are very difficult to follow; for example fiscal data seems to be invariably presented in a manner to maximise the apparent size of Japanese debt levels. I used to cover Japan as a rates strategist before 2006, and I have seen a lot of basic errors made by analysts who have used Japanese economic statistics without understanding their context. In order to avoid making similar errors myself, I will remain very general herein and do a deeper analysis of the data in later articles.

Theoretical Background


Why do I argue that the collapse in the JGB market will occur when it is in the national interest of Japan for this to happen? This is based on my preferred way of analysing the bond market. In summary (see linked articles for a longer explanations of these points):
  1. As per Modern Monetary Theory, government bonds act as a reserve drain; government spending creates reserves, and then bonds are issued to mop up reserves to keep interest rates from falling. This means that increased supply of bonds does not raise yields; in fact, we see the opposite pattern in practice.
  2. Government bonds are an asset of the non-government bond holders. This is an important insight of Stock-Flow Consistent modelling (and of Hyman Minsky, who can be viewed as a forerunner of Stock-Flow Consistent modelling). In order to disrupt the bond market, you need to disrupt the portfolio preferences of the private sector, which have considerable inertia.
  3. With supply and demand effects neutralised, bond yields instead track the expected path of the short-term rate. This rate is set by policymakers, and therefore rising bond yields have to reflect policymakers’ preferences.
  4. Quantitative easing does not work; all the Bank of Japan gymnastics with the monetary base have had no impact on the economy. Thus the inflation predicted by the Quantity Theory of Money has not happened.
These factors explain why previous predictions of the demise of the JGB market have not panned out.

Why would policymakers want the JGB market to collapse? There are two very good potential reasons.
  1. The Japanese domestic economy is growing rapidly, and inflation has become a serious concern. Rates will be hiked to moderate inflation*.
  2. The Japanese yen is falling in value, creating inflationary pressures. Policymakers will want a higher policy rate to increase the demand for the currency.
I will discuss these two possibilities in more detail below. (Note that the two scenarios could occur at the same time, as both can be viewed as variants of the same idea - the yen is losing purchasing power.) I believe the first possibility is the more likely of the two, but I imagine that many analysts will prefer the second.

This mode of thinking is probably alien to many people. I believe this is based on thinking about government finances in terms of household finances, or the Gold Standard experience (introductory economics textbooks often make assumptions that are equivalent to having a Gold Standard in place). If a bank offers you a mortgage for 4%, you do not respond by saying that the rate should be 5% in order to better regulate the operation of the economy. However, this is exactly how you have to think if you are the central government borrowing in a currency you control.

Rapid Growth Forcing Rate Hikes

Chart: Japan - A Long Way From Steady 5% GDP Growth

Policymakers historically have tended to follow the rule proposed by the neoclassical growth model: nominal interest rates ought to be close to nominal GDP growth rates. I think that rule is probably a bit of economic superstition, but it can be seen as an approximation to typical central bank reaction functions. As the chart above shows, Japanese nominal GDP growth has been well below the 5-6% level that would appear consistent with the collapse I discuss here. But it is seems too pessimistic to assume that this will be the case forever. Here are a list of possible reasons for faster real growth and/or inflation.
  1. Some serious fiscal policy moves to tighten the labour market (targeted job creation), or a properly targeted tax cut. (Previous fiscal policy moves were enough to stabilise the economy, but not cause an inflationary boom. My reading is that is exactly what was desired.)
  2. The labour market could be tightened up by reducing potential work hours. For example, increased maternity and paternity leaves in order to push up the birth rate.
  3. A new labour-intensive consumer good or service becomes a new large source of demand. This could be related to population aging, for example. Note that if it is a manufactured product, it may be that the production is automated and employs few people, but the installation is labour intensive.
  4. A booming export sector.
I do not see this growth boom happening in the near-term, but I may be missing something. It seems pessimistic (or complacent, if you are a JGB investor) to assume that this will not happen on a multi-year horizon.

One key issue is that it may be very hard to dislodge Japanese inflation expectations. Japan has achieved price-level stability, and it may be hard to convince locals that this will change. (This is in contrast to many foreign commentators, who obsess either about Japanese deflation or hyperinflation, or both at the same time.)
Chart: Japan CPI - Price Level Stability

Rate Hikes As A Currency Defence


A collapsing yen is a popular story among JGB bears, but I feel it is less of a risk than a domestically-led expansion.

The key vulnerability of the yen is Japan's need for energy  and other commodity imports; an upward spiral in energy prices could put the yen under immense pressure versus the currencies of energy producers. However, an upward spike in energy prices will simultaneously wipe out the purchasing power of other developed world consumers (particularly in the U.S.). As we saw in 2008, the global economy does not handle surging energy prices well. This limits the capacity of energy prices to remain at extremely elevated levels. It will take time to create the structural conditions we had in the 1970s that will allow the world economy to absorb energy price rises via a generalised inflation.

Otherwise, I find it hard to worry about the yen. The Japanese government has been intervening massively to hold down the value of the yen, and has an immense store of reserves to preserve its value versus other currencies without needing to raise rates.

Chart: Japan Has Persistent Current Account Surpluses, Not Deficits
And we cannot ignore the private sector holdings of non-yen assets. Given the configuration of the Japanese economy, with an aging population and slow domestic growth, we should expect that Japan would run persistent current account deficits. The earnings on foreign assets should be mobilised to finance the purchase of imports. The fact that Japan has been running current count surpluses makes it unsurprising that the yen has been uncomfortably strong.

For the foreseeable future, Japan will not need to attract foreign investors to finance a current account deficit; the economy only has to draw back a stream of proceeds from domestically-owned foreign currency assets. Given that domestic investors are typically managing their portfolios versus yen-denominated liabilities (financial debts or actuarial liabilities), they are more comfortable with Japan's optically low interest rates than foreign investors would be. 

 

A Final Note


If and when the JGB market collapses, there will be plenty of quotations by Japanese policymakers complaining about “too high” interest rates. This does not disprove my argument; it only shows that many individuals do not think very carefully about governmental finance. The policy rate will be hiked voluntarily by a committee of policymakers.

Bond yields will rise before the rate hikes; that is the nature of trading expectations. But unless policymakers ratify those rate hike expectations, bond yields will come back down again. For example, this has been the case for the past few years in the U.S.; the market has repeatedly priced in relatively aggressive rate hike paths, and the market was forced to back down each time. The fact that bond yields rise before rate hikes does not mean that bond investors force the rate hikes; bond investors were just doing their job within the current institutional framework of government finance. In other words, I am not worried about the so-called “Bond Vigilantes”.

* Many non-mainstream economists (in particular, MMT economists) have doubts about using rate hikes to control inflation. I have some sympathy to this viewpoint, but I will have to examine this some other time given the complexity of the subject. From the point of view of central bank watching, I expect the Bank of Japan would stick to the mainstream consensus that rate hikes are the best method to control inflation.

(c) Brian Romanchuk 2013

Sunday, September 29, 2013

Fujimaki: Japanese Hyperinflation By 2015!



Japan JGB 10-year bond yield - market collapse


One of the public services now provided here at bondeconomics.com is the tracking of outlandish forecasts about Japan and/or the JGB market. The first entry is provided by Takeshi Fujimaki, an ex-advisor of George Soros and now a member of the Japanese upper house of parliament.

I have enjoyed reading crackpot theories about the collapse of the JGB market since I started covering it around 2001, and this entry by Fujimaki looks like it represents the state of the art in this highly competitive field.


  • “Because the BOJ is buying huge amounts of JGBs, market principles in this country do not work.” The balance sheet of central banks throughout the developed world consist mainly of government bonds, and it has been this way for decades. The most successful means of determining bond yields consists of guessing what policy rate government bureaucrats will set. In other words, even slight familiarity with how government bond markets work will tell you that government bond yields are not really set by “market principles”. However, this statement will make him popular with all the gold bugs.

  • He has an outlandish bond yield forecast:               
Yields on 10-year Japanese government bonds may jump to 70 percent based on what happened in Russia when it defaulted in 1998, Fujimaki said. 
Sure, what happened to Russia is a great benchmark for a country with $1,135 billion in U.S. Treasury holdings (TIC data; July 2013) and no foreign currency debt.
  • He throws in an outlandish inflation prediction:
“If the yen goes up to 120 per dollar, Mr. Abe doesn’t need a third arrow,” according to Fujimaki, who expects the currency to drop to as low as 1,000 when Japan faces hyper-inflation in the next two years.  
Hyperinflation by 2015! Looks like liftoff is starting right now! Really going for the gold bug crowd.
Japan CPI index level

  • He ends of with a sensible-sounding bond-bearish call:
“The Olympics [in 2020 – BR]  will come at the time of a booming economy,” he said. During that period of economic growth “maybe 5 or 6 percent are reasonable levels for the 10-year yield.”
This is actually a very impressive stratagem. Even though his 70% yield forecast has a 0% chance of occurring, there is a chance there could be a “renormalisation” of rates within 7 years; why not? And if the 10-year does rise to something like 4% by 2020, he will be able to say “I told you so”.

What sets this apart, in my mind, is what he did not say.
  • He does not rely on debt-to-GDP ratios (but the reporter does mention them in the piece). Ten years ago, it was enough to state that the debt-to-GDP ratio was “unsustainable” and hence the JGB market was going down “soon”. But such a strategy is now suicidal, as the blogosphere is stocked with tons of charts on research on the (non-)impact of high debt-to-GDP ratios. (This is the result of a previous ill-advised academic paper on the dangerous impact of the 90% debt-to-GDP “threshold”.) 
  • He avoids setting a near-term target for JGB market collapse (like “a few months”). Only people with too much spare time on their hands will remember a blown forecast on a two-year horizon.

Of course, his worries (debt default and hyperinflation) are incompatible. In a hyperinflation, the monthly inflation rate is 50% or higher; so even an inflation-linked bond with a standard monthly computation period of one month will lose at least 50% of its purchasing power due to the indexation lag. If the yen collapses, the Japanese government need only sell a tiny sliver of its Treasury debt to buy back most of its debt. But why quibble, since there’s no chance of it happening anyway?

To be honest, the real story embedded in the Bloomberg article is that he wants to cut corporate taxes. The real logic behind his bizarre forecast:
  1. Lawmaker wants to raise corporate profit share of GDP at the expense of households.
  2. This is to be done by hiking the consumption tax rate, and cutting the corporate tax rate.
  3. Funnily enough, polls say such a policy is unpopular with the voters.
  4. So he makes up risks to the government bond market. 
  5. He then states that the rise in the consumption tax miraculously cures those risks. 

But to end off on a more serious note: this is part of a push to raise the Japanese consumption tax, which appears likely to occur. The theory is that the planned fiscal policy shifts are supposed to be neutral for growth, as there will be offsetting stimulus undertaken. I do not have a fancy model of the impact of their proposed fiscal changes, but it seems that they are effectively replacing “high multiplier” spending by “low multiplier” spending. In order for the impact to be neutral on growth, the fiscal deficit would have to be larger. Additionally, I am skeptical that businesses will take up investment incentives in the current sluggish growth environment – especially if domestic consumption falls due to the tax hike. And so, it appears highly possible that Japanese policymakers will drive their economy into recession yet again due to a foolish focus on fiscal ratios.


(c) Brian Romanchuk 2013