Recent Posts

Thursday, February 27, 2014

VAT Hikes And Inflation: U.K. Edition

Chart: Impact Of Indirect Tax Changes On UK CPI Inflation

One of the problems of studying inflation in a low inflation environment is that special factors may have a larger impact than underlying economic forces (like the output gap, wages or import prices). This makes inflation modelling difficult, and data interpretation is strained if you do not take those special factors into account. One of the largest impacts can occur from Value-Added Tax (VAT) hikes, which mechanically raise the price level in a country. The chart above shows the experience of the U.K., where various tax hikes raised CPI inflation by almost 2% in 2010-2011. Despite the belief that bond investors are supposed to have a Pavlovian aversion to inflation, this was actually bullish for bonds. I discuss this point here, as well as the issue of U.K. inflation sensitivity to the pound.

In 2010 and then again in 2011, the U.K. central government raised consumption taxes, which had the effect shown above on CPI inflation. In interests of space, I will avoid discussing whether hiking consumer taxes was a particularly good idea at that point in time. This hike, as well as the weakness in the British Pound (which I discuss further at the end of this article) meant that inflation broke well above the Bank of England's inflation target. This was despite the weakness in the economy, which was expected to lower inflation. The chart below shows how this move helped created a mini-"stagflation" panic in the U.K.
Chart: UK CPI and CPIY (ex-tax measure) Inflation

The chart shows CPI inflation, and the CPIY measure - in which indirect taxes are stripped out of prices. (The chart at the top, which is the direct measure of the impact of tax changes,  is not the spread between these two measures, rather it is calculated on the basis of holding tax rates constant relative to a reference period.)

The impacts of the tax hikes can be summarised from a number of points of view:

  • Growth: This is a restriction of fiscal policy, and growth would be expected to weaken in response. (And U.K. growth has been nothing to write home about, even if they managed to dodge a recession.)
  • Inflation: There is an obvious upward shock to the price level and this is a direct increase to the cost of living to U.K. citizens.  But even though the government did this two years in a row, it would not be able to do so indefinitely, so one should not expect this effect to persist forever (for example, within a personal financial plan).

    However, raising the measured CPI inflation rate is highly visible, and this could cause "second round" effects, as wage demands are increased (for example). This effect was present in the 1970's, and may be relatively more important in the U.K. than most other developed countries at present. Amongst the countries I covered, the U.K. appeared to have the largest inflation persistence, but that was less visible as inflation was stable near the Bank of England's target level. This persistence may mean why they appeared to be doing such a good job earlier in hitting their target.

    Note that if the U.K. does have a problem with inflation persistence like I suggest, then the impact of the tax hikes will be greater than shown in the chart above, which just measures the mechanical impact of tax hikes. Second round effects mean that later inflation rates will be raised by some amount, which would have to be estimated by a model.
  • Nominal Bond (Gilt) Investors: These tax hikes are a gift to bond investors, particularly if you are a foreigner who does not have to pay the higher VAT. (I have a small holding of gilts in ETF form, so all I can say is thanks.) The negative impact on growth is far more important than any second-round inflation effects. Even though the central bank is an inflation-targeter, they "looked through" the impact of taxes on inflation.
  • Inflation-Linked Bond (Gilt) Investors: If you owned a short-dated index-linked gilt, the upward shock to the price level is a gift. For longer maturity index-linked gilts, the effect is more ambiguous. There is the one-time shock to the price level, and possible second-round effects that are beneficial. However, tighter fiscal policy may lower longer-term inflation by more than the initial upward lift.
  • Currency: Tightening fiscal policy should lead to a stronger pound, but that is countered by the negative impact of weaker growth. I dislike imputing mechanical responses of the currency to domestic policy settings, as a currency is a relative price between two country's medium of exchange. Additionally, these mechanical rules of thumb relating policy moves to the currency would imply that economists would be able to make money reliably as currency forecasters. I avoided paying too much attention to the forex markets, but I saw no evidence of that happening.
Japan is about to undergo the same sort of experimentation shortly. People who forget to strip out the impact of taxes on the price level will probably declare "Abenomics" a success in terms of breaking the hold of inflation. The raising of consumption taxes will be restrictive for Japan, even though they are attempting to cut corporate taxes to balance the consumption tax hike. The reason why there will be a net tightening is because the same dollar amount of consumption taxes is much more effective in suppressing demand than the same dollar amount of corporate taxes. Since mainstream modellers avoid thinking about distributional issues as much as possible, this effect is ignored.

Currency Passthrough Into Inflation

Chart: British Pound/Euro Cross Rate

One of the impacts of the financial crisis was that the British pound cratered. This certainly raised the U.K. inflation rate by some amount, as imported goods prices would rise. The question is: by how much?

Based on the chart of CPIY inflation, the upper bound for the effect would have to be around 2% for a couple years or so. Based on the experience of other developed countries, outright deflation appears to be difficult to achieve. (The U.S. was hit a lot harder, and it still avoided deflation.) And I would emphasise that I view 2% as an upper bound, my guess would be a number closer to 1% or so. Given that the pound fell around 25% (using averages) versus the euro. this sensitivity does not appear extremely large. (Note that the trade-weighted pound fell by less than it did versus the euro; I do not have the time series handy.) In any event, the consumption tax hike generated a price level shock which was at least as large as the currency effect.

And like the VAT hike, currency falls cannot be sustained indefinitely (as long as inflation is controlled, like it currently is in the developed world). As a result, I do not worry too much about the value of the currency, as I discussed in this recent article.


Nevertheless, the other notable thing about these graphs is the strong upward trend in the UK's import ratio.  The decline in the exchange rate halts this for a while, but we can see that it is then starting to resume its upward course.  The growing propensity to import remains one of the UK's greatest long-term constraints.
I have never spent too much time analysing trade balance trends; my bias is that they are driven by industry-specific factors (anti-pollution regulations pushing dirty industries overseas), relative wage costs, as well as savings rates differentials. These are structural factors that move slowly, and are not easily dealt with by the standard macroeconomic policy levers. As a result, I do not have a firm opinion as to how strong the trade constraint that Nick Edmonds identified is.

(c) Brian Romanchuk 2014

6 comments:

  1. Brian,

    I feel the need to add a few more comments here on the exchange rate issue.

    The price impact of an exchange rate movement is not straightforward. For a start, suppliers of imports of finished goods will often react by shaving their prices, so the domestic price will not move by the same amount. On the other hand, it is not just import prices that change, because domestic producers that compete with importers may raise their prices. This particularly the case with commodity products. So we see big rises in the cost of food and energy, even where these are produced domestically.

    I believe however that the response is a relatively slow one, so even though the immediate impact of a depreciation may be only a small increase in the inflation rate, I would expect inflation to then be persistently higher for several years, eroding much of the real exchange rate movement.

    The main reason this has not happened in the UK is that wage growth has been so weak, which has been a result of the severe underemployment. The result has been steeply declining real wages since 2008. Had we had a normal employment market over this period, this is extremely unlikely to have happened, but the consequence is that higher inflation would have had to erode the real exchange rate movement much faster.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. I have just got my hands again on some UK data, and I do not have a wide enough data set to build some good models. Even so, it is difficult to estimate the effect if the lags are long, as there are so many other mving pieces,

      Delete
    2. I'm just basing it on the way I've modeled price setting in my model and the associated regression results I get. My econometrics is not that great though.

      Delete
  2. This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.

    ReplyDelete
  3. This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.

    ReplyDelete
  4. This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.

    ReplyDelete

Note: Posts are manually moderated, with a varying delay. Some disappear.

The comment section here is largely dead. My Substack or Twitter are better places to have a conversation.

Given that this is largely a backup way to reach me, I am going to reject posts that annoy me. Please post lengthy essays elsewhere.