Recent Posts

Wednesday, August 7, 2019

Yield Bugs

Joe Weisenthal has been causing a stir on Twitter discussing "yield bugs": people who have an ideological belief that bond yields out to be positive. This Bloomberg opinion piece discusses this, as well as some other comments on negative yields coming to the United States. I have not followed that debate too closely, as I initially assumed that there was not a whole lot of people who believed that bond yields ought to be positive. This is because bond yields are essentially determined by central bank expectations, and there is not a lot stopping central banks from pushing short rates to negative values.



Chart: U.S. Interest Rates
The figure above shows two key U.S. interest rates -- the Fed Funds rate, and the 10-year Treasury yield. Although the Treasury yield is set in a market, arbitrage relationships mean that it cannot march off completely independently of what the central bank is expected to be doing. It is not set by "savers" deciding what rate of interest they would like: as pension funds who failed to liability match discovered the hard way, "savers" in the bond market are price takers.

If the New Keynesians at the Fed want to march the Fed Funds rate negative, Treasury yields will follow suit. Yields can stay positive if investors expect a reversal of policy in the medium term, of course. However, given the track record of the New Keynesians, the policy rate is still stuck on tracks that are heading downhill. If a decent-sized recession hits within the next five years, it seems a near certainty that rates will end up as negative as the Fed thinks they can get away with.

The belief that "money" with a 0% interest rate will be an insurmountable barrier is a pipe dream: no large investor is going to stockpile bills in large amounts. Security is a nightmare (think about the plotline to the great Christmas film classic, "Die Hard"), and large amounts of cash are actually anti-liquid. The only plausible barrier are things in contract law, like the capacity to pre-pay taxes at no penalty. However, that only works for firms paying taxes -- which financial intermediaries managing assets for others do not.

The only thing that stops the Treasury curve from marching through 0% is the possibility that negative short-term rates -- which are literally a tax on bond investors -- would somehow causes the economy to accelerate. Given the complete lack of sustained acceleration in the major economies despite "unsustainably low" interest rates for decades, I would not suggest holding your breath waiting for that outcome. (Note: I re-wrote the first sentence of this paragraph since it could have been interpreted more strongly than what I meant.)

Update - Added Comments

After a certain amount of to-and-fro on Twitter, I realise that the previous text skipped over some issues. I will now add a couple of extra comments.
Chart: U.S. 10-Year Treasury, 30-Year Mortgage.

The first set of issues revolved around the banking system. Can the banking system survive negative rates? The first point to note is that banking systems in Europe and Japan have survived negative policy rates, and the policy rate is the linchpin of the risk-free curve, which is what matters for (central) government bonds.

Deposit accounts that yield 0% are an obvious concern for negative rate regimes. Since banks can extract fees from customers, they can work around the fact these deposits turn into a high-cost funding source to a limited extent. However, negative interest rates would eventually force institutional changes to banking (even if we put aside the possibility of abolishing cash, a proposal that I think is terrible).

Private sector lending rates are at spreads above the risk-free curve. Unless the risk-free curve is deeply negative, those lending rates can still be positive. For example, I show the 30-year conventional mortgage rate versus the 10-year Treasury yield: we see a fairly significant spread at all times. (Why the 30-year mortgage versus the 10-year Treasury? The 30-year conventional mortgage is an amortising instrument, and so the duration ends up being close enough to a 10-year Treasury for my purposes here. However, I didn't show the spread since mortgage trading exports would scoff quite loudly at me.)

We can expect stickiness around 0% for lending rates, but that does not help people who are buying and selling bonds in the secondary market.

But there is nothing inherently impossible about a negative lending rate. If we look at mortgages, they are priced off of the yields of residential mortgage-backed securities in the secondary market. Those bonds are normally high quality (e.g., backed by the CMHC in Canada), and so they can trade close to the risk-free curve. As a result, the secondary market mortgage rate can be negative, and eventually institutions will be offering new mortgages at negative rates.

The other issue is: how far can the central bank push the policy rate into negative territory? (With the previously noted concerns about the banking system being the issue.) I have doubts about how deeply negative the policy rate can go, and so there is some form of "lower bound" for bond yields. However, that lower bound is certainly not 0%, and one could imagine that experience with negative yields will allow that barrier to drop with time.

(c) Brian Romanchuk 2019

8 comments:

  1. We can think of money as representing value for work past-performed. Thus, when a worker completes a week of labor and is paid, the worker has a token of value. It follows that a project requiring weeks of sequential work will accumulate value (representing weeks of effort) owned by the laborer (represented by money) and project owner.

    In this scenario, the owners value is secured in increasing property value. The workers interest (being represented by money) is unsecured. Negative interest rates would guarantee that the worker will lose money on his share of the labor invested so long as he continues to hold money. This is unfair to the worker and gives an unearned advantage to the real property owner.

    In summary, negative interest rates do not help the worker.

    ReplyDelete
  2. “two key U.S. interest rates -- the Fed Funds rate, and the 10-year Treasury yield. Although the Treasury yield is set in a market, arbitrage relationships mean that it cannot march off completely independently of what the central bank is expected to be doing”

    But the Fed Funds rate is pretty much imaginary, and it has pretty much no role anyhow, because it applies only to "friends of friends" of the central bank. I can't walk into a Fed branch and borrow anything, never mind 10 billions, at the Fed Funds rate, and neither can an average business; in practice only extremely leveraged, very risky, and usually insolvent, finance conglomerates can do that.
    The same applies to the mortgage funds rate: only a property owner can borrow at the special "rich people" rate that is gifted to them by the central bank, even if borrowing on property is both highly levered and very risky.

    «Given the complete lack of sustained acceleration in the major economies despite "unsustainably low" interest rates for decades,»

    But the interest rates and terms charged to productive businesses and people are not "unsustainably low", they are huge, they range from 10-15% to 500-900% APR.

    The credit markets have been very strongly segmented by central banks, to ensure that enormous amounts of debt made available to "friends of friends" at very low rates don't cause wage inflation in the productive economy.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Fed funds is arbitraged against Treasury repo, and so it effectively matches the funding cost for Treasury positions. As a result, it’s a benchmark for pricing of the risk-free curve.

      Sure, private borrowers trade at a spread to that risk-free curve. However, lowering the risk-free curve should lower the rates faced by real economy borrowers.

      Delete
  3. «I have doubts about how deeply negative the policy rate can go, and so there is some form of "lower bound" for bond yields.»

    Indeed, as negative passive interest rates are in effect custodianship fees, that is how much customers of AAAA banks or businesses or governments are willing to pay for "return of capital" rather than "return on capital".

    ReplyDelete
  4. I still feel the big question is why is there still the belief that negative rates are stimulative? I just have not seen great evidence of the latter.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Yeah exactly. I don't see it either.

      Delete
  5. This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.

    ReplyDelete
  6. This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.

    ReplyDelete

Note: Posts are manually moderated, with a varying delay. Some disappear.

The comment section here is largely dead. My Substack or Twitter are better places to have a conversation.

Given that this is largely a backup way to reach me, I am going to reject posts that annoy me. Please post lengthy essays elsewhere.